Health Care Economics Analysis: The Price of Health Insurance

The price of health insurance is defined by the economic textbook as the fee for loading or the surplus after subtracting the premium from the expected payout. The price of health insurance can be measured using different ways. For example, as aforementioned, the price of health can be measured by subtracting the premium from the expected payout. Their difference is the price of health insurance. This price measure is based on load. The next way of measuring it is by using premiums to capture the increase in medical expenditures. The rise of the expenditure indicates that the technology has advanced. The rising premiums are associated with falling coverage. This can be attributed to the fact that, other than reflecting on desired medical expenditures, the premiums reflect on moral hazards. It can also be because of the ever-changing relative value of health insurance in comparison with the medical care that an individual would receive (Getzen and Allen, 247).

In the period between 1950 and 1980, the rapid advances in medical science and technology led to the establishment of medical care. There was a rapid growth of health expenditure, which accounted for 4.6% of the GDP. The price of health insurance was increasing continuously. The relative rate of increase in expenditure was great during the decades between 1950 and 1980. After 1980, the trend changed to 4.1% per year. This was mainly because of the introduction of Medicare and Medicaid in 1965. The rates of growth of the health expenditure since 1980 decreased. The new technology led to the spread of health insurance, both private and public. Since the prices for health insurance were high, groups, firms, and other organizations paid insurance for individuals making it affordable for them (Getzen and Allen, 251).

Adverse selection refers to the behavior of individuals who are vulnerable to high risks to look for health insurance. It also refers to the behavior of those who are at low risks or not vulnerable to any risks to defer from health insurance. When the individuals who are not vulnerable to any disease drop out of the pools of insurance, the act raises the cost of the people in the cover. In turn, this causes many to withdraw from the insurance cover. The ACA addresses the adverse selection by allowing the healthy population to transfer money to the insurers of individuals in vulnerable groups (Getzen and Allen, 258).

The medical loss ratio provision of the Affordable Care Act facilitates transparency in the marketplace and helps consumers to buy effective plans, which provide value for the money they spend. Individual or direct, pay a segment of 85% will qualify for the medical loss ratio. Small group segment (2 to 50 employees) of 90% and large group segment (51 or more employees) of 86% will qualify for the medical loss ratio. On the other hand, the individual/direct pay segment of 75% does not qualify for the medical loss ratio. Small group segment (2 to 50 employees) of 60% and Large group segment (51 or more employees) of 74% will not qualify for the medical loss ratio (Getzen and Allen, 261).

With the MLR, the health insurers are regulated to pay claims, clinical services, and other activities that can improve the quality of health care. It is also consumer-friendly. The health care costs will be lowered to favor people of all classes and the delivery of services will be improved (Getzen and Allen, 263).

The FDA drug approval process is overcompensating type 2 errors. Health spending is full of dynamics. For example, in 2010, the percentage of Medicare spent on prescription drug costs was 3.9. In 2012 and 2013, it rose to 4.2. The trend is expected to continue with time (Getzen and Allen, 271).

From the year 2006, prescription drug spending was increased to 18 percent. This was after the implementation of the Medical drug benefit. The Accountable Care Act will reduce prescription drug costs in Medicare (Getzen and Allen, 275).

Works Cited

Getzen, Thomas E, and Bruce Allen. Health Care Economics. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley, 2007. Print.

Cite this paper

Select style

Reference

StudyCorgi. (2022, April 22). Health Care Economics Analysis: The Price of Health Insurance. https://studycorgi.com/health-care-economics-analysis/

Work Cited

"Health Care Economics Analysis: The Price of Health Insurance." StudyCorgi, 22 Apr. 2022, studycorgi.com/health-care-economics-analysis/.

* Hyperlink the URL after pasting it to your document

References

StudyCorgi. (2022) 'Health Care Economics Analysis: The Price of Health Insurance'. 22 April.

1. StudyCorgi. "Health Care Economics Analysis: The Price of Health Insurance." April 22, 2022. https://studycorgi.com/health-care-economics-analysis/.


Bibliography


StudyCorgi. "Health Care Economics Analysis: The Price of Health Insurance." April 22, 2022. https://studycorgi.com/health-care-economics-analysis/.

References

StudyCorgi. 2022. "Health Care Economics Analysis: The Price of Health Insurance." April 22, 2022. https://studycorgi.com/health-care-economics-analysis/.

This paper, “Health Care Economics Analysis: The Price of Health Insurance”, was written and voluntary submitted to our free essay database by a straight-A student. Please ensure you properly reference the paper if you're using it to write your assignment.

Before publication, the StudyCorgi editorial team proofread and checked the paper to make sure it meets the highest standards in terms of grammar, punctuation, style, fact accuracy, copyright issues, and inclusive language. Last updated: .

If you are the author of this paper and no longer wish to have it published on StudyCorgi, request the removal. Please use the “Donate your paper” form to submit an essay.