Takeover Defenses in International Practice

Introduction

The unique and defining feature of a hostile takeover is that the management and board of directors of the target company resist the proposed transaction. In order to overcome their opposition, the bidder wishing to gain control over the target company directly approaches and appeals to the target’s shareholders.

Hostile takeovers were predominantly present in the middle of the 1980s both in the U.S.A and in the U.K, particularly when acquirers found there to be a large discrepancy between a particular company’s assets and its relative stock market value. Nobody seemed safe during this period of 1980-1990 when around 30% of the Fortune 500 companies faced one or more takeover attempts, over 50% of them explicitly hostile. Although studies indicate that this takeover wave has benefited the target companies’ shareholders, companies’ management who feared losing their positions and associated private benefits have raised objections to this phenomenon.

In light of the enhanced pressure by the company’s management and as hostile bidders became more aggressive and creative, companies and their lawyers searched for new techniques to either prevent the hostile takeover or to increase the target’s leverage in negotiating a favorable deal. One of those newly developed techniques was the poison pill (the “Pill”) which is still considered one of the most remarkable but also controversial innovations in corporate law practice in the U.S.

Conscious of the extensive experience in the U.S., and as the hostile takeover attempts have begun to spread to other countries, foreigner companies have also started to consider enlarging their takeover defense arsenal and to adopt Pills and other antitakeover measures. However, although hostile takeovers are always colorful affairs all around the world, one of the most striking differences between U.S. and foreign corporate law over the last thirty years is the further flexibility of U.S. companies and in particular their board of directors to implement defensive measures aimed at discouraging hostile bidders.

In recent years, as globalization marches forward, one might argue that a cohesive and unified international approach towards takeover defenses is essential. This may bridge information asymmetry and reduce transaction costs associated with foreign investments, disincentives countries from adopting takeover policies oriented to defend their local interests and prompt overall cross-border transaction activity.

The first section of this essay describes the various common antitakeover measures, the pros and cons of these measures and empirical studies regarding their impact on companies’ values. The second section reviews and analyzes major differences in takeover regulations among several countries, focusing on the recent attempt to harmonize national takeover rules in Europe under the EU Thirteenth Directive on takeover regulation (the “Directive”). The following section addresses the question of whether a cohesive international approach towards takeover defenses is recommended. This section will give a normative analysis of the effectiveness of the different legal frameworks in Europe and the U.S. in light of the different types of ownership structures common in those regions. The last section of this paper suggests hidden virtue of adopting takeover defenses in certain foreign markets.

Hostile Antitakeover Measures

Shark Repellents

Shark repellents are provisions in the incorporation documents of a company which are adopted by the shareholders to discourage unwanted takeovers. They can be generally divided into the following main categories:

Controlling Changes in the Board of Directors

The most common technique is to classify the board’s members into three separate groups of which only one may be elected each year (“Staggered Board”)8. It basically provides antitakeover protection by both

  1. forcing any hostile bidder to wait at least one year before gaining control over the board; and
  2. requiring the hostile bidder to win two elections far apart in time.

A study examining the impact of Staggered Board provision on hostile bids in the U.S. during the five-year period 1996-2000 concluded that these provisions reduced the returns of shareholders of the target company by 8-10%. In addition, a research study conducted in 2005 indicated that Staggered Board is systematically associated with lower company value since it insulates the directors from the vital market for corporate control.

Therefore, it is not surprising that during the years 2000-2004 board declassification proposals have experienced a dramatic rise in support at the shareholder voting stage. These findings can explain the fact that the percentage of S&P 500 firms employing a Staggered Board has shrunk from 56% in 2004 to 34% in March 2009. However, a study conducted in 2007 indicates that Staggered Board may actually benefit shareholders as it found that shareholders of companies with Staggered Board received a larger proportional share of the total value gains from a merger.

Additional common techniques to restrict a change in the board are removal for “cause only” or by supermajority vote of the shareholders and prohibiting cumulative voting.

Shareholders Actions Provisions and Majority requirement

Those types of provisions designated to limit the flexibility of a bidder to call for and obtain a shareholder vote regarding either director removal or approval of the transaction. A provision requiring a supermajority vote will usually stipulate certain events like a bid to takeover, which require higher level of approval than the default rule of the applicable corporate law. This can be accompanied by a fair price provision which exempts transactions from the supermajority requirement if the price to be paid by the bidder exceeds a specified amount.

Additional provisions in this respect may include a requirement to provide adequate notice and supply information before a proposal is brought to the shareholders meeting and a prohibition to bypass procedural requirements by using shareholders’ written consent.

Stakeholder Clause

This type of provision usually stipulates that the board is authorized to consider the impact of its decisions on various stakeholders (employees, suppliers, host communities etc.). This may offer an overt legal footing to decline any takeover attempts.

Poison pills

The Pills which were described by John C. Coat as “the most common, controversial, and distinctive type of defense” were developed as a reaction to the panic created by the 1980s hostile takeover wave in the U.S. The Pills are usually special purpose “shareholder’s right plans” which in the U.S. as well as in Japan may be initiated and approved by the board without the need to acquire the shareholders’ consent unless otherwise specified in the company’s incorporation documents. In other jurisdictions, like France and Canada, in which Pills are legal and in practical use, shareholders’ approval for adopting Pills is required.

The essence of the common Pill is to encourage a potential bidder to deal with a target company’s board in order to avoid substantial dilution. The Pill usually specifies certain triggering events, such as commencement of a tender offer or purchase of a specified percentage of the issuers’ stock without the board’s approval, upon which the shareholders have the right to buy either the stock of the target company (“Flip-In”) or the acquirer’s stock (“Flip-Over”) at a significantly discounted price.

A Flip-In provision is generally much more powerful defense than Flip-Over, partly since Flip Over provision will not deter a bidder who is not planning a merger with the target company. However, modern pills usually include both features. It should be noted that the Flip-Over device is not allowed under some jurisdictions, such as France, that recognize only the legality of the Flip-In provision.

The Pill may include a back-end provision, according to which the target’s shareholders are allowed to exchange their rights for a package of the target securities valued at the present minimum fair value of the target set by the board. This Pill is usually redeemable if the bidder’s offer exceeds such price and therefore it basically establishes a minimum fair price at which the bidder can cash out the securities’ holders. In addition, debt securities issued under the Pill may prevent bidders from selling target’s assets or increasing its debt, precluding his option to finance the acquisition from the target’s own resources.

Another type of Pill which was invalidated by many jurisdictions, including several states in the U.S. stipulates a voting provision which involves with the issuance of preferred stocks with special voting powers to the target company’s common shareholders (excluding the acquirer). Therefore, the result might be a severe dilution in voting power of the hostile acquirer.

The last types of Pills which should be mentioned confront the possibility that the perspective acquirer will conduct a proxy or equivalent procedure (if applicable) in other jurisdictions to ask shareholders to vote for his proposal onto the board and thereafter to redeem the Pill. Those types of Pills include the dead end provision which stipulates that the Pill may be redeemed only by those directors, who had been in office when it was adopted, or their successors, and the no hand provision which specifies that the Pill is nonredeemable for six months after a change of control in the board.

However, Delaware Supreme Court invalidated the dead hand Pill for violating Delaware statute and constituting disproportional defensive tactic and the no hand Pill for conflicting with the statuary right of directors to manage the business of the company.

Since the hostile bidder can usually ask shareholders to vote for his propose onto the board and thereafter redeem the Pill, the Pills do not exclude the possibility of a hostile takeover but rather create a delay. This delay makes takeover more expensive in light of costs associated with soliciting shareholders votes.

However, in most takeover battles those costs are relatively minor. Therefore it seems that the main costs derived from the fact that since the market values may fluctuate rapidly, deals that cannot be concluded rapidly are frequently of lesser values. From the target company’s perspective, although these costs may be reflected in the proposed price, the Pill, especially when combined with Staggered Board provision, may provide the board with substantially more time than would be provided by the law to consider the offer and search for competing bids.

For example, in 2007, AirTran launched a tender offer for Midwest Air and won a proxy fight for one third of Midwest’s Staggered Board. Midwest’s Pill prevented AirTran from purchasing the tendered shares and its Staggered Board prevented AirTran from quickly gaining control of a majority of the board to redeem the Pill. Midwest then put itself up for sale on the market and received from TPG Capital an offer of 13% above the price offered in the original takeover bid.

Self Tender and Greenmail

Boards’ power to deal selectively in companies’ own stock has emerged as a powerful defensive measure. The company may offer to purchase its own stocks from current shareholders at a higher price than that offered by the hostile bidder. Greenmail is a practice in which the target company enters into a contract to repurchase company’s stock owned by a shareholder threatening to gain control over the company, typically in exchange of shareholder’s consent not to initiate a contest for control over the company for a particular phase of the period. Since the premium payments are unavailable to the other shareholders, this practice, resulting from apparent takeover threats, has caused much debate and is illegal in several jurisdictions, including for example Australia. Other jurisdictions, such as Japan, impose severe procedural and financial restrictions on this practice and therefore its effectiveness there is limited.

Golden Parachute and Pension Parachutes

Golden parachutes are severance contracts between the company and its top executives providing benefits in the event of a change of control or termination of the executives’ employment in other specified circumstances. The pension parachute provides usually for the vesting of increased pension benefits to be paid out of the pension fund’s surplus assets in the event of an unfriendly change of control. The main defensive feature is that raiders may want to use these surplus assets to finance the acquisition.

Although golden and pension parachutes may certainly deter potential bidders, they are usually not explained by antitakeover concerns but rather on the ground of protecting employees’ reasonable expectations and provide them with security.

Loans

The target may borrow loans which will be immediately due in the event of a hostile takeover. Therefore the bidder may find himself taking over company which owes a large amount of money immediately due.

Cross shareholdings

Cross shareholdings is a mechanism in which controlling block of shares are held by “stable shareholders” in order to prevent other companies from targeting them for acquisition. Stable shareholders include, for example, members of the same enterprise group, banks, directors, employees and customers.

This tactic is traditionally common in Japan as Japanese companies and their financial banks constitute business groups by holding each other’s shares. It should be noted that since the early 1990s the use of cross-shareholdings decreased significantly in Japan as well as in other countries in which it was widely used such as France and Germany.

Litigation

In order to delay the consummation of the hostile bid, the target’s management may try to initiate

legal proceedings against the bidder. The proceedings will usually be based on alleged violation of an applicable corporate law or antitrust regulations. A study conducted by Jarrell to examine the effectiveness of this tactic, concluded that if the management is not blocking other competitive offers, this tactic can extract a higher takeover premium for the shareholders. It was reported that in 62% of the cases when the target company uses this method, there were other competing offers proposed to the stockholders in comparison to only 11% of the cases where such offers were not made. This frequently resulted in takeover premiums.

White Knight

Under this strategy, the company’s management pursues a White Knight, meaning a friendly probable acquirer which will offer the company a better deal. It is commonly agreed that this tactic usually enhances shareholders’ wealth. Nevertheless, opposing views argue that it may cause losing the original bid and that since shareholders typically face collective action problems, competing bids could actually lead to a pressure to tender, forcing shareholders to accept the later offer even if the prior bid is more convenient for them.

Crown Jewel and Lockup Option

Defensive restructure may take a form of spin-offs, defensive acquisition or sale of crown jewel (one of the target’s key assets) in order to make the target less attractive to the bidder.

In order to demonstrate the lockup option technique an example will be used. Assume that a hostile bidder “A” offers to purchase at 40$ per share a target company which owns a valuable asset (e.g., oil field). The board approaches a favorable white knight “B”, who also offers 40$. In order to ensure that favorable bidder “B” will win the contest, the board provides him with the prevailing advantage of an option to purchase the oil field for a fixed sum. If “A” increases his offer, “B” can still purchase the oil field for a fixed sum and “A” may find himself paying a high price for a valuable asset which will be taken out of the company.

The downside of those tactics is that the board may find it hard to justify that they were in good faith and in company’s best interests if they were not under consideration before the takeover attempt.

Pac-Man Defense

Under this strategy, the target Company would react to the hostile takeover attempt by conducting an attempt of its own to take over the original raider.

Defensive Acquisitions

Acquisition of another company might have a defensive value since the target may become less attractive for the bidder following such an acquisition either in light of the resulting scale of the company, its increased leverage or due to the creation of potential regulatory or antitrust issues. Particularly, acquiring companies in certain highly regulated industries (i.e. banks), or companies engaged in the business area of the bidder, may expand the grounds for antitrust challenges to the takeover attempts and discourages a bidder who might not be willing to endure the risk and time associated with obtaining the necessary regulatory approvals. The main risk under this tactic is that the company will use its resources for unbeneficial purchases at excessive prices.

Recapitalization

The common forms are merger recapitalization in which the common shares are converted into a combination of cash and/or debt as well as to new common stock of the surviving company or a reclassification recapitalization, in which common shares are reclassified as preferred stock which are in turn redeemed for cash and/or debt as well as to common stock. The purpose of recapitalization as a defensive tactic is to make the deal less attractive for the bidder by threatening him with dilution or increased company debt. The threat of dilution may be also achieved through a newly created or enlarged employee stock option plan.

Restructured Voting

The purpose of this tactic is to concentrate voting power in friendly hands in order to frustrate the ability to gain effective control over the company. The common technique is to issue dual class Common Stock when usually the lower voting shares carry more rights regarding dividends, liquidations and transferability. This practice was traditionally common in Europe in the pre-Directive era, while in the U.S., it was and still is primarily used by start-up or closely held companies. In Japan, companies may issue shares without voting rights but it is unlawful to grant one common stock with multiple voting rights. It should be noted that in most jurisdictions publicly held companies are prohibited from issuing dual class stocks under the applicable corporate law or as in the U.S. under the domestic securities exchanges regulations.

The Advantages of Antitakeover Measures

One of the most common and frequently discussed problems in the field of corporate governance is the cost associated with the separation between ownership and control and the fact that the interests of corporate management and corporate shareholders do not always align (the “Management Agency Problem”). The assumption that directors are acting as shareholders’ direct agents seems problematic when considering scattered shareholders’ inability to properly supervise directors. The attempt of company’s management to entrench themselves through the employment of takeover defenses is a fundamental aspect of the Management Agency Problem. It is argued that the mere threat of a hostile takeover incentivizes managers to maintain efficient levels of performance and more completely align their interests with those of the shareholders. Therefore, employment of takeover defenses increases the Management Agency Problem and particularly the risk of managers’ misconduct.

Another argument against the usage of antitakeover measures emphasizes the potential harmful consequences both at the macro-economic level and for the shareholders themselves. It is widely agreed that takeovers are usually a wealth-maximizing, positive phenomenon, since they enable replacing inefficient management with a more efficient one and promoting the allocation of resources to a higher use value. This argument is also backed by empirical studies concluding that hostile takeovers tend to increase the value of the target company.

The significant impact of antitakeover measures on the actual frequency of hostile bids is illustrated in the table attached as Exhibit A, which specifies the significant higher percentage of hostile takeovers initiated and consummated in the U.K. in which Pills and other defense measures are less frequently used, in comparison to the U.S. It should be noted that several commentators claim that hostile takeovers lead to redistribution of wealth, rather than the generation of additional wealth.

The Disadvantages of Antitakeover Measures

The following arguments are typically used to justify adoption of antitakeover measures:

  1. Antitakeover measures can increase the bargaining power of the company. Scholars claim that targets with strong takeover defenses will extract more in a negotiated acquisition than an unshielded target company since the acquirer’s no-deal alternative in the event of a hostile bid is less attractive compared with a strong-shielded target. The Pill or other measures may provide the board with more time to consider an offer and to simultaneously solicit a competing bid. Therefore, if the bidder is eager to consummate the transaction or if other competing offers are at stake, it can encourage him to increase their offers. In addition, the shareholder may have a collective action problem which will lead them to accept irrational decisions. The board may negotiate with potential buyer much better than the scattered body of shareholders and therefore by binding themselves ex ante, the shareholders may be able to improve their collective position ex post.
  2. The management usually holds private and inside information concerning the company’s real value and has superior skills to evaluate the contemplated transaction. Therefore, antitakeover measures may protect shareholders’ interests by enabling the board to prevent a transaction that undervalues the company.
  3. Defensive measures may mitigate distorted managerial incentives. The threat of hostile takeover may increase the managers’ incentive to adopt a strategy focused on maximizing short-term profits at the expenses of long-term strategy. An increase in company value and shareholder satisfaction may prevent hostile takeovers but may prove detrimental for the long term interest of the company. For example, according to Stout (2002), takeover strategies may offer a new company enough time to wholly implement its business plan and to upgrade employees’ skills.
  4. Supporters of the corporate social responsibility approach claim that the central role of companies in the modern society constitutes a responsibility towards third parties such as employees, consumers, and suppliers as well as towards the community in which it operates in general. Since shareholders tend to focus solely on their economic benefit, it is argued that Stakeholders Clause is required to consider the impact of takeovers on such third parties.

Empirical Review

Studies of companies’ stock prices when they adopt new antitakeover measures provide a clear indication that companies’ stock prices decrease in the wake of news that the company has adopted antitakeover measures. However, the evidence regarding the impact of antitakeover measures on takeover premium and shareholder return are more inconsistent.

According to Jarrell and Poulsen (1987), takeover defenses have ended on average in negative changes in target company share price. Similarly, the Comment and Schwert study conducted in 1995 revealed that the majority of takeover defenses like supermajority provisions, staggered board, reincorporation, fair price provisions and dual capitalization have ended in a slight decline in shareholder returns, of about 0.5%. Similar research results were also found in previous empirical studies including Jarrell and Poulsen (1987), Malatesta and Walking (1988), Ryngaert (1988), Karpoff and Malatesta (1989) and Romano (1993).

Bebchuk and others (2005) built a “management entrenchment index” that is negatively correlated to a company’s value. The index includes restrictions to amendments to a shareholder bylaw, staggered board, supermajority requirement, golden parachutes and Pills. The above study’s chief finding is that the companies with low entrenchment index where the interest of management is more in line with those of shareholders have higher unusual returns than companies with a high entrenchment index.

However, as was already briefly demonstrated in Section 2.1.1 above regarding Staggered Board, there are some opposing findings with respect to the impact of takeover defenses on shareholders have a good effect on returns to shareholders if the company management would employ such a guard to enhance the purchase price during takeover negotiation. Other studies (e.g., Field and Karpoff (2002)), found no significant impact of takeover defenses on returns of shareholders.

An interesting explanation given to the inconclusive evidence regarding the impact of takeover defenses is that the opportunity to significantly benefit or lose from them is foreclosed due to the delicacies of market forces. They provide the target company with bargaining power but simultaneity divert takeover activity to unshielded companies so eventually the market may reach a unique equilibrium that strikes a balance between shielded and unshielded companies.

In conclusion, in spite of some inconsistency, the empirical evidence appears to highlight that takeover defenses normally tend to have a negative effect on shareholder return. Nevertheless, when they are not used just to entrench the management but rather as a delaying tactic without blocking other competing bids, antitakeover measures, including Pills and Staggered Board, may have a welcome effect.

Recent Trends in the U.S.

Until 2007, U.S. Companies were largely and gradually dismantling their takeover defenses. At the end of 2007, about 1,400 U.S. companies had Pills in force in compared to 2,200 companies at the end of 2002. In 2007, the percentage of S& P companies with Pills had come down to 30% from 60% in 2002. This derived mainly from pressure and actions of institutional shareholders as part of their attempts to gain further control over companies.

2008 seemed to indicate a turnaround point as it was the first year since 2005 in which there was a year-on-year increase in the number of companies adopting Pills. However, it seems to be only a reaction to the market meltdown and the surge in the hostile takeover activity rather than a turning point as in March 30, 2010 it was reported that the number of U.S. incorporated companies with Pills in effect was in the lowest level since 1990.

Takeover Defenses Around the World

Takeover regulation and in particular the extent to which a company is entitled to adopt takeover defenses differs significantly from one jurisdiction to another. Even among countries in which companies are allowed to and do indeed adopt Pills, the related procedures differ significantly, particularly with respect to the need for shareholders’ approval and whether the Pill can be automatically triggered upon a hostile attempt, or an active decision by the board is required.

A table comparing the use of Pill, Staggered Board, unequal voting rights, cross share-holdings, as well as specifying the compulsory bid requirements and fundamental market characteristics in France, Canada, Japan and the U.S. is attached as Exhibit B.

Japan

In light of the increased hostile takeover activity in Japan in the last decade, many Japanese directors and managers looked for an authority to adopt more effective defensive measures. Amendments in the Commercial Code of Japan in 2005 have legalized new antitakeover measures, including the Pill, to defend Japanese companies from hostile takeovers. The U.S. takeover legal framework was the guideline for the Japanese policymakers designing the current takeover regulations which clearly follow the American model rather than the European one. Under the code, Japanese directors have wide discretion in implementing antitakeover measures and shareholder approval is not required for the adoption of a Pill.

Nevertheless, Japanese courts have promoted the principle that companies will receive shareholders’ approval to assure that the Pills are a reasonable measure and proportional to the actual threat. Therefore, not surprisingly, out of the 382 listed Japanese companies that adopted Pills as of July 2007, 218 of them had received prior shareholder approval.

The Pills in Japan are usually a “pre-warning defensive scheme”, according to which the companies disclose in advance the management’s possible countermeasures to be employed upon hostile takeover as well as the type of information and waiting period that they would demand that the bidder observe. In contrast to the U.S. where the Pill is automatically triggered, in Japan the board must actively exercise the Pill.

Therefore, although Japan generally followed the American takeover legal framework, Japanese companies have more restriction on the use of antitakeover measures than their American counterparts. Japan’s first Pill was exercised on July 12, 2007 by Bull-Dog Sauce Co. in order to dilute the stake of Steel Partners, which launched hostile bid over Sauce.

Some scholars have raised their concerns that the Pill “has the potential to be greatly more pernicious in Japan than it has been in the United States”. Firstly, it was argued that the institutional infrastructure that plays a major role in mediating the market for corporate control and limiting the use of the Pills in the U.S. (i.e. Delaware Courts, institutional shareholders) do not exist in Japan to the same extent. Secondly, the potential advantage of increasing bargaining power is doubtful since managers in Japan do not like to negotiate with unsolicited bidders and therefore have tried to design Pills as devices to definitively defeat hostile bids.

E.U.

After fifteen years of debate, the E.U adopted in 2004 (effective as of May, 2006), the Thirteenth Directive on takeover regulation in an attempt to harmonize national rules of takeover in Europe. Some of the most fundamental rules of the Directive are as follow:

  1. The compulsory bid rule, according to which a bidder must make a bid for all the outstanding shares of the target company after acquiring a certain percentage of its shares.
  2. The board neutrality rule, according to which the directors of the target are held to a strict rule of neutrality. This rule differs significantly from takeover regulations in the U.S. where the board has a lot of discretion to adopt defenses if they have reasonable grounds to believe the takeover is a threat and the measures that were taken are themselves reasonable. In practical terms, this rule allows, for example, the white knight defense but imposes restriction on the adoption of a Pill by the board.
  3. The breakthrough rule which prohibited the use of multiple voting rights shares to thwart hostile bids.

The member nations of the E.U. have been given an option to opt out from the board neutrality and the breakthrough rules. The Directive therefore does not exclude the use of Pills but it is optional for each member nation whether to apply the restriction or not. Thus, their respective national rules on takeover defense strategies are still relevant depending upon on each specific scenario. However, most European counties follow the approach of the board neutrality rule and the adoption of takeover defenses is entrusted directly to the shareholders themselves.

France

France elected not to demand companies to pursue the “breakthrough rule”, thus strengthening takeover defense supported by French market characteristics like multiple voting rights, shareholders agreements and Pills. The March 2006 Takeover Directive legislation made by France enable boards to use Pills if permitted by a 2/3 vote of the shareholders during the hostile bid. However, companies may elect to exempt themselves from the need to receive shareholders’ approval during the bid, if the shareholders grant the board authority in advance (which may be valid for no more than 18 months) to directly trigger the Pill. In addition, unlike the U.S., the Pill cannot be automatically triggered upon hostile bid and the board must take a positive decision in this respect. A Flip-Over Pill is illegal under French law.

Scattered Board and Dual class shares are very common in France but the effectiveness of the former is limited as the shareholders are entitled to dismiss directors without a cause. White knight was relatively common defense in France in the pre-Pill era. France has also had one attempt to use Pac-Man defense in 1999 when Total Fina made a hostile bid for an oil company. The target had attempted to make a counter offer to takeover Fina through a share swap, but afterwards withdrew this offer.

U.K.

The City Code on Takeovers and Mergers inflicts a rule of impartiality on the target directors by banning the employment of defenses without the shareholder assent. In contrast to the U.S. takeover system in which board may independently adopt several antitakeover measures both before and after the takeover attempt, the City Code allows only pre-bid measures. Thus, management wishing to entrench itself could take the benefit of less harsh ex ante rules to push in takeover defense strategies well ahead of any bid. As boards are prohibited under the “passive rule” from taking any action which will frustrate the takeover offer or deny the shareholders opportunity to decide on this offer, the City Code takes a shareholder–oriented approach in which the shareholders have a final say with regard to the usage of defensive strategies. Pills are nearly impossible to implement under the U.K. takeover rules and common defensive measured in the U.K. involve white knights or Self-tender.

Coherent International Approach to Takeover Regulations

The further flexibility that U.S. companies traditionally had to implement defensive measures led to a significant gap between the actual use of different measures, especially Pills by U.S. companies in comparison to companies in the U.K., France and Japan. This is illustrated in the table attached as Exhibit C regarding the years 1991-2005. It should be noted that as described in this paper above, since 2005 Japan and France legalized the use of the Pill and there seems to be an increase in adoption of antitakeover measures in those countries as well as elsewhere in Europe. Although, as described in section 5 above, the U.S. market experiences an opposite process, the basic distinction that American companies and their boards enjoy further flexibility to implement takeover defenses, still applies.

The lack of a coherent international approach towards takeover defenses may lead to inefficient results derived from the interests of each country to defend its local companies. As it is commonly agreed that the tendency of investors to invest in companies located in their own geographical region is primarily linked to concerns about information costs, a unified takeover approach can mitigate this information barrier and prompt cross-border transaction activity.

Scholars have provided various explanations for the differences in takeover regulation around the world, emphasizing cultural and historical reasons. For example, it is argued that a fundamental reason for the shareholder-oriented approach in Europe when compared to the U.S. is the social democrat ideology prevalent in Continental Europe. Other scholars have explained the differences in the political power of interest groups. For example, it was argued that the shareholder-oriented approach in the U.K. derived from the larger role of British institutional investors in shaping the takeover legal framework in comparison to their American counterparts.

The aforementioned explanations might enable us to understand the evolution of different approaches but do not necessarily address the question of whether there should be a unified approach or not. The fundamental question which should be examined in this respect is whether the differences also derived from the need to address distinctive objective market problems.

I would address this issue by analyzing the differences between Europe and the U.S. The U.S. and the U.K. systems are characterized by dispersed ownership and strong securities markets (“Widespread Structure”). In contrast, in Continental Europe and most other countries around the world, share ownership is typically concentrated in a controlling shareholder or a coalition of a few major shareholders and is characterized by pyramid structure (“Concentrated Structure”). This different ownership structure has two main implications with respect to the challenges facing the policymaker:

  1. Companies in Concentrated Structure market are naturally less exposed to hostile takeovers in light of the existence of strong blocking controlling shareholders affiliated with the management. As already discussed above, it is widely agreed that takeovers are generally a wealth-maximizing positive phenomenon. Therefore, the breakthrough rule and the natural board rules which impose restrictions on companies to adopt takeover defenses may be explained by the desire of the policymaker in a Concentrated Structure market to prompt and facilitate takeovers to a larger extent.
  2. In a Concentrated Structure market, the Manager Agency Problem is mitigated by the existence of controlling shareholders affiliated with the management on the one hand, but on the other hand, the potential expropriation of the minority shareholders’ wealth by the controlling shareholders significantly increases. Accordingly, the Manager Agency Problem is largely replaced by an agency conflict between the minority and controlling shareholders (“Shareholder Agency Problem”). The compulsory bid rule addresses this issue by prompting distribution of the controlling premium to the minority shareholders and enabling them a fair opportunity to exit in case of an undesirable change of control.

As described in this section 7 above, the distinguished market structure leads to unique problems which the policymaker should address. Therefore, it is justified to adjust takeover regulations to the distinct market characters and relevant problems of a particular jurisdiction.

Takeover Defenses and Concentrated Structure Markets

Although several scholars have argued that the differences in takeover regulation in the U.S. and Europe indeed mirror the basic distinctions between the most common ownership structures in each region, it would be difficult to justify under this claim that the gap between the regulations in the U.S. and U.K., and the similar approach taken by the U.K. and countries characterized as Concentrated Structure markets around Europe and elsewhere in the World.

Specifically, it seems that in light of the absence of an extensive Management Agency Problem, the general hostility towards takeover defenses in the U.S. should not necessarily apply to a Concentrated Structure market. In addition, as will be briefly explained below, as opposed to the prevailing current practical legal situation, it might be more efficient to prompt and encourage Concentrated Structure companies to implement antitakeover measures.

According to Bebchuk, the Concentrated Structure is frequently derived from the fear of hostile takeover as well as from the ability of the controlling shareholder to benefit from the control. Moreover, Bebchuk and other scholars have raised their concern that in order to maintain disproportionate control over the minority shareholders in the pre Directive era, European companies would simply switch from a previous common dual class share structure to a more Concentrated Structure, thus preventing any possibility of takeovers.

The Israeli market may provide an interesting confirmation for the aforementioned theory. The Israeli market is traditionally Concentrated Structure market in which hostile takeovers are seen as almost an impossible task. However, in February 1998, Mr. Tshuva, at that time a second-tier building contractor, managed to consummate a hostile takeover of Delek Group, then Israel’s second-largest gas company with a major shareholder holding 34% of the shares.

An empirical study conducted in 2003 has proven that this hostile takeover, the biggest and most famous in the history of Israel has caused major shareholders in other Israeli companies to increase their holdings to further concentrate control and prevent hostile takeover attempts. Another study conducted in the U.S. found that CEOs of Forbes 500 firms that became protected by new state antitakeover legislation reduced their holdings of shares by an average of 15%, apparently because the shares were not as necessary as before for maintaining control.

The aforementioned findings support scholars’ claims that takeover defenses may be useful devices to promote Widespread Structure and signal that the ownership structure will remain such in the future.

Since hostile takeovers are more likely to occur in Widespread Market, permitting and encouraging companies to adopt takeover defenses in Concentrated Structure markets may paradoxically increase the probability of hostile takeovers. Shifting to a more Widespread Structure market will also benefit the overall market by increasing liquidity, a valuable feature of a Widespread Structure market which enables it to maximize its value. This process will also benefit the minority shareholders by mitigating the Shareholder Agency Problem. The controlling shareholders will enjoy the prospect of diverting part of their investment to other companies and diversifying their portfolio.

Conclusion

The negative effect of takeover defenses mainly rests in the increasedng the Agency Management Problem and restricting the generally wealth-maximizing positive phenomenon of takeover activity. On the other hand, the positive effects can be seen in increasing the target’s bargaining power, mitigating shareholder collective action problem and overcoming several market failures as described in this paper.

The active debate over whether takeover defenses benefit shareholders was fuelled by the inconsistent results of different studies conducted in order to examine the impact of takeover defenses. In spite of some contradicting findings regarding the impact of these defensive measures, particularly Pills, on takeover premium, these empirical studies indicate that takeover defenses tend to have a negative effect on share price and shareholder return and therefore be detrimental to the interest of shareholders.

Theoretically, the most persuasive argument against adopting takeover defenses derives from the Management Agency Problem. However, in Concentrated Structure markets such as Continental Europe, Japan and Israel, the existence of strong blocking controlling shareholders affiliated with the management mitigates the Management Agency Problem. This problem is largely replaced by the Shareholder Agency Problem which is less common in Widespread Structure markets such as the U.S. and U.K.

As policymakers in Concentrated Structure and Widespread Structure markets face different challenges, takeover regulations should be adjusted to the individual market characteristics and relevant problems. Therefore, a unified approach towards takeover regulations will not be efficient in terms of corporate governance.

This essay further suggests that the general hostility towards takeover defenses in the U.S. should not necessarily apply to Concentrated Structure market. In fact, adopting takeover defenses in Concentrated Structure markets may paradoxically increase the practical probability of takeovers as controlling shareholders will be less threatened by a reduction in their holdings. Shifting to a more Widespread Structure market will benefit both major shareholder who will be able to diversify their portfolio and minority shareholders by mitigating the Shareholder Agency Problem. In addition, this process will benefit the overall market by increasing liquidity and prompting takeover activity.

Although in the long term, this process may lead to the creation of the Management Agency Problem and other Widespread Structure related problems, it seems that the benefits of Widespread Structure markets overshadow the potential problems. Accordingly, as opposed to the prevailing current practical legal situation, it might be more efficient to restrict the flexibility of U.S. based companies to implement antitakeover measures but conversely to prompt their use in the context of Concentrated Structure markets.

It should be noted that in recent years alongside the decrease in adoption of antitakeover measures in the U.S., there seems to be an increase in their adoption in France and other Concentrated Structure markets in Europe. Even in Israel, some companies have recently adopted Pills based on the model employed by companies in U.S.. However, until additional companies in Continental Europe, Israel and other Concentrated Structure markets follow in their footsteps and further research is conducted on the practical implications of this phenomenon on ownership structure and hostile takeover activity, the practical accuracy of the theory suggested herein is yet to be proven.

Exhibit A

Location of Target Announced M&A (Public Company Targets) Hostile Hostile Completed
Number Percentage Number Percent
U.S.A 54,819 312 0.57 75 24
U.K 22,014 187 0.85 81 43
M & A Hostility in the U.K and U.S -1990-2005. Source: Armour J. and Skeel D.

Exhibit B

France Japan United Kingdom United States
Recapitalization 0 0 2 0
Repurchase 0 0 0 3
Self- Tender 0 0 5 4
Packman 1 0 1 1
Greenmail 0 0 0 0
Poison
Pill
0 0 2 76
White Knight 4 1 20 23
Defensive Measured Used in Hostile Takeover Attempts, 1991-2005 (538 attempted hostile deals). Source: Varieties of Capitalism.

Exhibit C

Market Canada France Japan USA
When Poison Pills introduced? 1986 2006 2005 1984
Hostile Takeovers? Yes. Robust market for corporate control Rare Rare Frequent
For Poison Pills, is shareholder approval required? Yes Yes. Unless reciprocity exception applies Not clear. Practically, most companies receive approval No
Whether Board action needed to issue pills or automatic trigger When an acquirer buys some threshold of shares , automatically triggers. Board action required Board action required When bidder buys some threshold of shares , automatically triggers.
Level of Board Independence Majority independence is market best practice 1/3 of independence required Predominantly non-independent Majority independence is required
Staggered Board Rare Yes Directors tenure is restricted to 2 years Decreasing. Nowadays a minority of S& P 500 companies
Unequal Voting Rights Yes. Dual class stock common Yes. Common No Infrequent
Cross-Share holdings? Rare Occasionally, with preemptive shareholder agreements Yes. But much less than in past Rare
Mandatory Bid Acquirer who reaches 20% threshold is obligated to make a formal bid / sell down. Squeeze-out rights: 90% trigger Triggered by acquisition of over 33.33% of the voting rights/capital or over 2% within less than one year by persons holding 33% – 50% of the voting rights. Squeeze-out and sell-out rights: trigger: 95%. Mandatory bidrule introduced in 2006. Trigger: two-thirds issued share capital. Federal takeover regulations require: 1) non-discrimination among shareholders; 2) any increase in offer price during tender offer period must be made to all shareholders who have tendered their shares.
Major Block holders (>20% of Shares) Not uncommon – particularly through dual class share Common common (but not in companies with poison pills) Very rare , particularly of bigger companies
Poison Pills And Market Characteristics. Source: Institutional Shareholder Services.

Bibliography

Books

  1. Brown M., Ferreara R., Bird P., Kubek G. Takeovers: a strategic guide to merger and acquisition (2001).
  2. Gorzala, Jeannette, The Art of Hostile Takeover Defence (2010) London: Books on Demand.
  3. Stephen M. Bainbridge, Mergers and Acquisitions (2 ed., 2003).
  4. Karpoff , Marr & Danielson, Corporate Governance and Firm Performance New York: Wiley Blackwell (2007).
  5. Fleischer, Arthur Jr. & Sussman A., Takeover Defense, Mergers and Acquisitions, new york: aspen publishers (2010).
  6. Hunt, p. a., Structuring Mergers & Acquisitions: A Guide to Creating Shareholder Value Aspen publishers online (2004).
  7. Loss, Louis & Seligman Joel., Fundamentals of Securities Regulation, London: Aspen Publishing Online (2004).
  8. DePamphills, Donald M., Mergers, Acquisitions and Other Restructuring Activities. London: Academic Press (2009).
  9. Gaughan, Patrick A., Mergers, Acquisitions and Corporate Restructurings. New York: John Wiley & Sons (2007).

Articles and additional resources

  1. Hannes S., The Hidden Virtue of Anti-takeover Defenses, 24 Cardozo L. R. 1903 (2003).
  2. Davis G., Stout K., Organization, theory and the market for corporate control: a dynamic analysis of the characteristics of large takeover targets, 1980-1990, 37 admin Sci. Q., P. 605 -633 (1992).
  3. Armour J. and Skeel D., Who writes the rules for hostile takeovers, and why? The Divergence of U.S. and UK Takeover Regulation, Georgetown Law Journal, Vol. 95, 1727 (2007). Web.
  4. Bebchuk L. and. Fried J., Executive compensation as an agency problem Discussion Paper No. 421 04/2003 Harvard Law School. Web.
  5. Greene E., Curran A. and Christman D., Toward a Cohesive International Approach to Cross- Border Takeover Regulation, 51 U. Miami L. Rev. 848 (1997).
  6. Bebchuk L. and Ferrell A., A New Approach to Takeover Law and Regulatory Competition, 87 Virg. Law Rev. 111 (2001).
  7. Bebchuk L., Coates j. & Guhan Subramanian, The Powerful Antitakeover Force of Staggered Boards: Theory, Evidence, and Policy, Stanford Law Review, Vol. 54, 2002, 887.
  8. Bebchuk, Lucian A., and Alma Cohen, The Costs of Entrenched Boards, Journal of Financial Economics, 78, 409-433 (2005).
  9. Loring J. & Taylor K., Empirical Study, Shareholder Activism: Directorial Responses to Investors’ Attempts to Change the Corporate Governance Landscape, 41 Wake Forest L. Rev. 321, 331 (2006).
  10. Bates, T., Becher, D. Lemmon, M., Board classification and managerial entrenchment: Evidence from the market for corporate control, Journal of Financial Economics 87(3), 658.
  11. Coat J., Takeover defenses in the shadow of the pill: A critique of the scientific evidence, 79 Tex L. Rev. 271, 277 (2000).
  12. Till Lefrance, Poison Pills in a Comparative Perspective, Posted by Robert Jackson, Managing Editor, Harvard Law School Corporate Governance Blog. Web.
  13. Animashaun, Babatunde M., Poison Pill: Corporate Antitakeover Defensive Plan and the Directors’ Responsibilities in Responding to Takeover Bids, Southern University Law Review 18 (1991) 172.
  14. Hannes S, The Market for Takeover Defenses, 101 Nw. U. L. Rev. 125 (2007).
  15. Robinsin E., Watchell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz (Aug. 20, 2007) ”Classified board once again prove their value to shreholders in takeover battle”. Web.
  16. Goldan H., Hostile Takeovers in Japan: Are they in the Cards, 1 Touro J. of Trans. Law 375 (1990).
  17. Scher M., Bank-firm Cross-shareholding in Japan: What is it, why does it matter, is it winding down? 2001 Discussion Paper No. 15. Web.
  18. Institutional Shareholder Services, Poison Pills in France, Japan, the U.S. and Canada, Takeover Barriers Rise in Europe and Japan, But Fall in North America, 2007. Web.
  19. Jackson G., Miyajima H., Varieties of Capitalism, Varieties of Markets: Mergers and Acquisitions in Japan, Germany, France, the UK and USA (2007). Web.
  20. G. Jarrell, the wealth effects of litigating by target: Do intersts Diverge in a merger, 28 journal of law and economic 99 (1985). Web.
  21. Lynden Griggs, Golden Parachutes, Crown Jewels and the Arrival of the White Knight, Canberra L. Rev 213 (1998).
  22. Mucciarelli F., White Knights and Black Knights: Does the Search for Competitive Bids Always Benefit the Shareholders of ‘Target’ Companies? European Company and Financial Law Review, Vol. 3, Issue 4 (2006), pp. 408-425 Mucciarelli, Federico M.
  23. P. Burdett, National Markets and New Defenses: The Case for an East Asian Opt-In Takeover Law, 20 Colum. J. Asian L. (2007) 385.
  24. Guhan Subramanian, Bargaining in the Shadow of Takeover Defenses, Yale L.J. 621 (2003) p 621. Web.
  25. Hannes S, Private benefits of control, Antitakeover Defenses and the Perils of Federal Intervention, 2 Berkeley Business Law Journal 263 (2005). Web.
  26. White & Case, Poison Pills in an Increasingly Hostile Environment. 2009. Web.
  27. Jessica Hall, “Poison pills drop to lowest level in 20 years”. Web.
  28. Yaplip R., Taking the Poison Pill? The pressures of globalizations on the Japanese economy and intellectual property (2008). Web.
  29. Baum H., Takeover Defenses in Japan: Corporate Value Reports and Guideleines. Web.
  30. Ronald J. Gilson, the poison pill in japan: the Missing Infrastructure, 2004 Colum. Bus L. Rev. 21, 31. Web.
  31. Osugi K., What is Converging? Rules on Hostile Takeovers in Japan and the Convergence Debate, Asian-pacific law & policy journal, V. 9 (2007), p. 157.
  32. Gelter M, The Dark Side of Shareholder Influence: Managerial Autonomy and Stakeholder Orientation in Comparative Corporate Governance, Har. Inter. L. Journal., Vol. 50 nu. 1 (2009).
  33. Suzuki, Katsumasa, Future Prospects of Takeovers in Japan Analyzed from the View of Share-Ownership Structures and Laws in Comparison with the United States and the European Union Columbia Journal of Transnational Law, Vol. 42, Issue 3 (2004).
  34. Cuervo A., Corporate Governance Mechanisms: A Plea for Less Code of Good Governance and More Market Control, 10 Cor. Gov. Vol. 10, Nu. 2, (2002) p. 91.
  35. Hannes, S. Justifications for the Use of Anti-Takeover Defenses in the Israeli Market, 26 Tel Aviv U. L. Rev. (2002-2003) 838.
  36. Bebchuk L. and. Fried J., Executive compensation as an agency problem, Discussion Paper No. 421 04/2003 Harvard Law School. Web.
  37. Gorga E., Cornell Law Library Scholarship@Cornell Law: A Digital Repository Cornell Law Faculty Working Papers Faculty Scholarship 9-24-2008 Changing the Paradigm of Stock Ownership from Concentrated towards Dispersed Ownership? Evidence from Brazil and Consequences for Emerging Countries. Web.

Cite this paper

Select style

Reference

StudyCorgi. (2022, May 5). Takeover Defenses in International Practice. https://studycorgi.com/takeover-defenses-in-international-practice/

Work Cited

"Takeover Defenses in International Practice." StudyCorgi, 5 May 2022, studycorgi.com/takeover-defenses-in-international-practice/.

* Hyperlink the URL after pasting it to your document

References

StudyCorgi. (2022) 'Takeover Defenses in International Practice'. 5 May.

1. StudyCorgi. "Takeover Defenses in International Practice." May 5, 2022. https://studycorgi.com/takeover-defenses-in-international-practice/.


Bibliography


StudyCorgi. "Takeover Defenses in International Practice." May 5, 2022. https://studycorgi.com/takeover-defenses-in-international-practice/.

References

StudyCorgi. 2022. "Takeover Defenses in International Practice." May 5, 2022. https://studycorgi.com/takeover-defenses-in-international-practice/.

This paper, “Takeover Defenses in International Practice”, was written and voluntary submitted to our free essay database by a straight-A student. Please ensure you properly reference the paper if you're using it to write your assignment.

Before publication, the StudyCorgi editorial team proofread and checked the paper to make sure it meets the highest standards in terms of grammar, punctuation, style, fact accuracy, copyright issues, and inclusive language. Last updated: .

If you are the author of this paper and no longer wish to have it published on StudyCorgi, request the removal. Please use the “Donate your paper” form to submit an essay.